Evidence that HB 2001 is deeply flawed

There is extensive, credible evidence that HB 2001 is deeply flawed

The sponsors and supporters of HB 2001 have been unable to present credible evidence or analysis that HB 2001 will help address the true “housing affordability” crisis by increasing the supply of rental housing that’s affordable to Very Low Income (VLI) and Extremely Low Income (ELI) households. The single, unsupported theory used to justify HB 2001 is that increasing the production of new housing, no matter the type or cost, will — by the “law of supply-and-demand” — lower the cost of all housing and thus make more existing housing units affordable to VLI and ELI households. This “trickle-down” theory has been debunked by numerous studies and analysis.

House Bill 2001 is neither rational nor evidencebased.

The discussion below supports Rational, EvidenceBased, Transit-Oriented Development.

This discussion presents evidence that the proponents of HB 2001 have no idea of the scope or nature of its potential impacts, and that HB 2001‘s crude approach to increasing density would not provide a meaningful measure of improvement in housing affordability. From comments made by several legislators’ policy directors, it seems clear that an underlying belief by these staff (and presumably the legislators they serve) is that the State must take control of zoning details because the local planners and elected officials have failed. And yet, there couldn’t be better evidence than HB 2001 (and several other housing-related bills) to demonstrate that State-level planning is likely to be much worse. From the legislative, it appears the state’s own planners have not even produced maps showing the geographic scope of HB 2001 and the existing zoning for the ten largest cities (Portland, Salem, Eugene, Gresham, Hillsboro, Beaverton, Bend, Medford, Springfield and Corvallis).

Even after voluminous testimony challenging the assumed benefits of HB 2001, there isn’t a single explanatory or supporting document listed under the “Analysis” tab on the HB 2001 web page. Seriously? And the paltry and developer-oriented amendments that were adopted further confirm the impression that no independent, competent planner(s) have been involved. In other words, proponents of HB 2001 support a radical upzoning on a massive, statewide scale and convinced legislators to approve it without the slightest idea of it’s scope or impacts. That’s not wise planning or judicious legislative decision-making.

This isn’t an academic issue. Along Eugene’s W. 6th/7th Aves. West Eugene EmX Extension corridor, which runs generally east-west, there is a solid, two-block (north-south) wide extent of commercially-zone property that allows multi-family development and/or mixed-use development with no density maximum and buildings up to 120 feet high. (Yes, ten to twelve story apartments of unlimited density!) Off-street parking requirements are between 1/2 to 3/4 of a space per apartment, and this parking doen’t have to be located on the same lot or development site. And yet, there has been zero, zip, nada apartment development along this corridor since WEEE became fully operational. H2010 won’t change anything about this zoning, so the bill won’t do a thing to encourage medium- or high-density, Transit-Oriented Development development. Instead, HB 2001 will incentivize much lower density away from transit services.

Contrary to proponents’ claims, HB 2001 is likely to encourage displacement in more-affordable, single-family neighborhoods that are near to WEEE. According to professionals knowledgeable about Eugene’s commercial and apartment development conditions, there are two main causes for lack of apartment development on commercial lots adjacent to WEEE. 

  • First, although the existing commercial development is low-end, one-story in nature, the cost to purchase such a property and clear it for development is prohibitively high.
  • Second, apartments adjacent to either of the 3- and 4-lane major corridors would not be attractive to high-end renters or condo owners. 

Thus, the potential rental or sale return is far less than necessary to warrant the cost and risk of development. The solution to that is multi-faceted, but certainly includes making Multiple-Use Property Tax Exemptions (“MUPTE”) available.

Close behind, to the north of W. 6th Ave. and to the south of W. 7th Ave., are two of Eugene’s most affordable neighborhoods: The “Westside” neighborhood (the northern half of the Jefferson Westside Neighbors organization’s area) and the “Whiteaker” neighborhood. Both neighborhoods have a full range of housing types including single-family detached, ADUs, duplexes, triplexes, fourplexes, cottage clusters, courtyard low-rise apartments, and larger multi-unit apartments. In addition there are a number of “transitional” housing facilities run by social service agencies. The housing in these neighborhoods still includes many very small, basic, “post-war” homes with no yard or just a very small yard. There’s no “luxury” housing at all. These are neighborhoods that underwent substantial exodus, disinvestment and decline during the 1950s and 1960s; and, at that time, a priority of the (more competent) Eugene Planning Division was preventing these areas around the city center from degrading into slums. 

According to local real estate investment professionals, these neighborhoods are “ripe for the picking,” particularly if fourplexes or apartments are allowed on existing lots. Some of the residential lots have a single, small, poorly-maintained house, which is rented at the low-end of the market. Such properties are much lower cost than any of the commercial properties. The low-cost lots that are two or three blocks from W. 6th Ave. or W. 7th Ave. sit in attractive, though modest single-family areas. Thus, these lots are primed for “scrape-and-build” development of much higher-rent apartments or higher-priced condos. Based on expert analysis and direct local experience, HB 2001 is almost certain to create significant displacement in these areas.

So, where is the state planners’ analysis of the effects that HB 2001 would have on these neighborhoods? Nowhere! Trust us — We know better than you.”

As mentioned above, the unsupported, even unexamined, “belief” upon which HB 2001 depends is that radical upzoning of single-family neighborhoods will produce substantial new housing; and by the “law of supply-and-demand,” the result will be overall lower housing costs. In contrast to the complete absence of any supporting evidence for this “belief,” there’s ample, real-world evidence that this upzoning won’t produce much housing and will likely increase costs.

To start, the recent exposure of the deceptive, gross overstatement of what the Portland “RIP” upzoning would produce perfectly reflects the way developer advocates have spewed false information and wrapped themselves in the cloak of “housing affordability.” Unfortunately, too many well-intentioned folks, including legislators, have bought the story without responsibly examining the real evidence.

Consider the following recent report on the experience of a Portland area city, Vancouver, Washington:

https://www.columbian.com/news/2018/nov/19/vancouver-reviews-status-of-affordable-housing/

“‘But as the council pointed out, the city can’t build its way out of the affordable housing crisis.’ Councilor Bart Hansen said when the city first began really taking a look at affordable housing a few years ago, the party line was if you build more units, prices will go down. Essentially, Hansen said, supply and demand would fix the problem. ‘What we’re seeing now is the availability is going up and the price is not going down,’ he said.

It turns out, at least in Vancouver, supply and demand is not enough to remedy the housing crisis.

‘People are struggling with paying their rent every day’ said Peggy Sheehan, the city’s community and economic development programs manager. ‘There has been some trickle down that’s rumored to happen, but we aren’t seeing it.‘”

Housing pricing is driven by complex factors, many of which are context-sensitive; and the “product” is not like corn or toilet paper. The “product” is extremely variable and the pricing has segments and tiers. A limited supply in the high-end condo segment doesn’t necessarily shift the demand for that product permanently to a lower tier or a different housing type or area. For the most part, only supply in an “affordable” tier will affect prices in that tier.

And here’s recent, very reliable research that puts the lie to the “beliefs” upon which HB 2001 depends. As reported by density-lovers’ favorite, CityLab, recent gold standard” research from MIT finds:

“[Yonah] Freemark reaches two startling conclusions that should at least temper our enthusiasm about the potential of zoning reform to solve the housing crisis—conclusions that, interestingly enough, he has said he did not set out to find. First, he finds no effect from zoning changes on housing supply—that is, on the construction of newly permitted units over five years. (As he acknowledges, the process of adding supply is arduous and may take longer than five years to register.) Caveats and all, this is an important finding that is very much at odds with the conventional wisdom.

Second, instead of falling prices, as the conventional wisdom predicts, the study finds the opposite: Housing prices rose on the parcels and in projects that were upzoned, notably those where building sizes increased.”

https://www.citylab.com/life/2019/01/zoning-reform-house-costs-urban-development-gentrification/581677/

Freemark cautions that his study doesn’t necessarily “invalidate the basic laws of supply and demand.” But he also emphasizes that “[w]e need to approach neighborhood rezoning carefully.” Unfortunately, that’s exactly what the Oregon legislators who approved HB 2001 did not do!

Other solid research establishes the substantial risk that blanket upzoning poses. In “Neighborhood Upzoning and Racial Displacement: A Potential Target for Disparate Impact Litigation?,” published last year in Journal of Law and Social Change, researcher Bradley Pough not only raised substantial legal exposure that might arise from the overly-broad reach of HB 2001, his research also found:

“In this way, upzoning changes are taking part in the same underlying activity as exclusionary zoning tactics: maximizing the value of land in the hopes of attracting or retaining mobile capital. The perhaps not so obvious corollary to this activity is that, by maximizing the value of land, residents and elected officials are gradually pricing out consumers who can no longer afford this product. In the case of exclusionary zoning, these consumers are the low-income minorities who, but for the cost, would move to the desirable suburb. In the case of upzoning, these consumers are often the low-income minority renters already living in the neighborhood who are gradually pushed out (i.e. displaced) due to higher rents and pricier surrounding amenities.

* * *
In each of these neighborhoods, conscious decisions by the city government and developers to upzone particular areas resulted in an increase in average rents, a reduction in affordable housing units, an increase in white residents, and a noticeable reduction in the neighborhood’s minority populations.”

Again, this isn’t academic since the Whiteaker neighborhood, mentioned above, has a significant number of Hispanic households because it has some of Eugene’s lowest-priced homes and apartments, as well as access to support services, such as Centro Latino Americano.

* * * * *

SUMMARY

There may, of course, be legitimate debate about the role of density in housing policies, and there are studies that at least partially support a positive role that higher density limits can play in addressing housing affordability, particularly by encouraging medium- to high-density apartments on well-served transit routes.

But HB 2001 proposes a sweeping and radical transformation of neighborhoods of all sorts and uprooting the lives of residents across the entire state without a shred of analysis of the areas and impacts that would be affected. HB 2001 is an irredeemably simplistic law with incalculable risks.

No reasonable representative of Oregon citizens should in good conscience allow this bill to remain in the Oregon Revised Statutes.